England - Periods - Tudor 1485-1603

The Poor Laws

Placeholder image

The Poor Laws were a series of measures enacted in Tudor England to address the issue of poverty and vagrancy. They were created in response to the economic and social disruptions caused by the Reformation, the dissolution of the monasteries, and the enclosure of common lands.

The first Poor Law was passed in 1536 during the reign of Henry VIII. It required that each parish provide for its own poor, either by giving them alms or by setting them to work. The law also authorized the creation of overseers of the poor to manage the system of relief.

The second Poor Law was passed in 1597 during the reign of Elizabeth I. It required that each parish appoint two or more overseers of the poor, who were responsible for collecting a poor rate from the inhabitants of the parish and using the funds to provide relief to the poor. The law also established the categories of "deserving poor" (such as the elderly, sick, and disabled) and "undeserving poor" (such as able-bodied vagrants).

The expected outcome of the Poor Laws was to provide relief for the poor and prevent vagrancy and begging. The actual outcome, however, was more complex. The system of relief created by the Poor Laws was often inadequate and relied heavily on the discretion of individual parish officials. Some parishes were more generous in providing relief than others, leading to disparities in treatment for the poor. In addition, the laws were not always effective in preventing vagrancy, and the problem of poverty and homelessness persisted throughout the Tudor period.

The Poor Laws were also criticized for their harsh treatment of the "undeserving poor," who were often subjected to harsh punishments such as whipping and imprisonment in workhouses. The laws were seen as reinforcing social inequality and failing to address the underlying causes of poverty.

it is generally believed that a significant portion of the population was living in poverty or close to it.

One estimate suggests that as much as 25% of the population in Tudor England was living in poverty, with another 25% living just above the poverty line. These estimates are based on records of people receiving poor relief or charity, as well as anecdotal evidence of widespread poverty and social unrest.

For those who could not support themselves, there were a few options available. One was to rely on the support of family and friends, who might be able to provide food, shelter, or other assistance. Another option was to rely on the charity of the church, which often provided alms and other forms of assistance to the poor.

In 1536, the first Poor Law was passed, which required each parish to provide for its own poor. This led to the establishment of a system of poor relief, which was administered by overseers of the poor and funded through a poor rate levied on local residents. The system of poor relief was not perfect, and there were often disparities in the amount and quality of relief provided by different parishes. Nonetheless, it did provide a basic safety net for those who could not support themselves.

For those who were unable to find support from these sources, the consequences could be dire. The poor and homeless might be forced to beg, steal, or engage in other forms of criminal activity to survive. They were also vulnerable to disease, malnutrition, and other health problems, which could be exacerbated by living in unsanitary or crowded conditions.

Overall, the situation for the poor in Tudor England was difficult, and there were few options available for those who could not support themselves. While there were some forms of assistance available, they were often inadequate and inconsistent, and many people were left to fend for themselves in extremely difficult circumstances.

Inflation & the Poor

The dissolution of the monasteries, the sale of church properties, and the use of the accumulated funds were closely linked to the inflationary forces that affected Tudor England. Here's how:

Dissolution of the monasteries: The dissolution of the monasteries was a policy instituted by Henry VIII in the 1530s that involved the confiscation of monastic lands and the dissolution of monastic orders. The monasteries were a major source of economic power and land ownership in Tudor England, and their dissolution allowed the Crown to gain control over vast amounts of wealth and property.

Income to the Crown: The sale of church properties and monastic lands provided the Crown with a significant source of income. The proceeds from the sales were used to fund various initiatives, including the building of ships and the financing of wars. This influx of cash allowed the Tudor monarchs to expand their power and influence.

Inflationary forces: The influx of cash from the sale of church properties and monastic lands contributed to the inflationary forces that affected Tudor England. The sudden influx of money into the economy led to an increase in prices for goods and services, as there was more money chasing a limited supply of goods. This inflation had significant impacts on the economy and society, including rising prices, social unrest, and economic instability.

Spending on other items: The Crown's spending of the accumulated money from the sale of church properties and monastic lands on other items also contributed to the inflationary forces. The Crown's spending increased demand for goods and services, leading to higher prices and further inflation.

Overall, the dissolution of the monasteries, the sale of church properties, and the use of the accumulated funds were important factors in the economic and social changes that occurred during the Tudor period. While these policies provided the Crown with significant power and resources, they also had significant impacts on the economy and society, including inflationary pressures and social unrest.

The inflation that occurred during the Tudor period had a significant impact on the poor, who were the most vulnerable members of society. Here are some of the ways in which inflation affected the poor:

Rising prices: The inflationary pressures of the Tudor period led to a general increase in the prices of goods and services, including basic necessities like food and clothing. The poor, who were already struggling to make ends meet, found it increasingly difficult to afford the things they needed to survive.

Decreased purchasing power: Inflation also decreased the purchasing power of the poor. Even if they were able to earn a living wage, the increased prices meant that their money went less far than it had before. This meant that the poor were forced to make difficult choices between necessities like food and rent.

Unemployment and underemployment: The inflationary pressures of the Tudor period also contributed to high levels of unemployment and underemployment. As prices rose, employers found it more difficult to keep up with wage demands, and many workers were left without a steady income. The poor, who were already at a disadvantage in the labor market, were particularly vulnerable to these trends.

Social unrest: The inflationary pressures of the Tudor period also contributed to social unrest and political instability. The poor, who were often the most marginalized members of society, were more likely to take part in protests and demonstrations, as they had less to lose by doing so. These protests often focused on issues like rising prices and unemployment, and they sometimes turned violent.

Overall, the inflation that occurred during the Tudor period had a significant impact on the poor, who were already struggling to make ends meet. The rising prices, decreased purchasing power, unemployment, and social unrest contributed to a difficult and often precarious existence for many people.

If you have a suggestion regarding additional topics you would like to see included - please let us know

Reference: Article by Greg Scott (Staff Historian), 2024

i

History & Heritage

Access History creates and posts content, articles, and subject matter relating to history and heritage
Copyright 2025 to Clio Society. All rights reserved and images and logos are created and presented for the general use of the public and educational institutions All content is the responsibility of Access.
Use of this website constitutes acceptance of Access terms and conditions
Placeholder image